Some conservatives oppose new housing on the ground that exclusion will “save” their neighborhoods from poor people. Is there any response to these arguments?
This year, the governor of New York, Kathy Hochul, sought (unsuccessfully) to actually do something about housing costs, proposing a “Housing Compact” which would force municipalities to liberalize their zoning to allow more housing within their borders. If you read planning journals and law reviews, you might think the primary resistance to this proposal would be from urban socialists, but in fact, the most aggressive opposition came from relatively moderate suburbs, especially in Long Island.
This opposition is based on a idea that some writers pejoratively refer to as “right-NIMBYism”: the idea that new housing is dangerous because it might actually succeed in reducing costs, thus bringing an influx of poor people into a suburb, thus creating crime and white flight. For example, conservative commentator Kevin Williamson writes that politicians such as Gov. Hochul want “to wreck the unwrecked neighborhoods to make up for all of the housing stock in areas that have been rendered undesirable or positively unlivable.” More decorously, Judge Glock defends zoning because allowing lower-income people into a suburb allows them to get “high-quality services by skimping on low-quality property with lower taxes.”
Right-NIMBYism is based on fear that zoning change will be too successful: that by reducing housing costs, deregulation will lead to an influx of crime-creating, non-taxpaying poor people into suburbia. By contrast, left-NIMBYs claim that new housing actually increases housing costs, and that zoning actually protects the poor from gentrification. (I have responded to their arguments in a variety of articles).
It seems to me right-NIMBYism is harder to combat than left-NIMBYism. Left-NIMBYs, to the extent that they really believe their arguments, can sometimes be persuaded that the law of supply and demand applies to housing. But right-NIMBY arguments aren't really based on objective concerns about the public good; rather, they are based on fear and self-interest.
Admittedly, one right-NIMBY concern—the idea that change in the status quo equals the end of suburbia—is an obvious lie. There are plenty of suburbs in the Sun Belt with more apartments and far lower rents than Long Island, and many of them are as desirable as any other suburb. But from a typical suburbanite's perspective, status quo bias might make this argument unpersuasive: even if you don't think that Great Neck will turn into the South Bronx, why take a chance?
But even if you assume all rich suburbs will stay rich, right-NIMBYism is hard to combat. Here's why: in the short run, some homeowners benefit from high housing costs. As housing becomes more and more expensive, their homes become more valuable. But suburban homeowners get an extra benefit: when housing prices go up enough, more people become homeless. Visible homelessness makes urban centers less desirable, because unhoused people are more numerous and visible in downtowns full of homeless shelters and social services. And as downtowns become less desirable, suburbs look better in comparison, and become even more valuable.
So, in the very short run, restrictive zoning essentialy gives suburban homeowners a license to print money. By creating a regionwide housing shortage, they can not only make houses more valuable generally but, by making downtowns less desirable, make their suburban property especially valuable. So why should anybody support change?
One possible argument is that free-market principles support less or no zoning. But since most homeowners are not ideologues (or, in New York's suburbs, even conservative or Republican), this is not likely to persuade many.
Another possible argument is that even if it is rational for each individual suburb to maximize home values, it is not rational for the region as a whole. When housing costs reach the levels of downstate New York or coastal California, sooner or later people start moving to cheaper parts of the nation. And where people move, jobs will eventually follow. When jobs go away, sooner or later, the tax base goes away, and exploding home values are canceled out by exploding property taxes and declining government services.
This argument requires homeowners to look more than fifteen minutes into the future. And that's the hard part.
Plan to Potentially Remove Downtown Milwaukee’s Interstate Faces Public Scrutiny
The public is weighing in on a suite of options for repairing, replacing, or removing Interstate 794 in downtown Milwaukee.
‘Forward Together’ Bus System Redesign Rolling Out in Portland
Portland is redesigning its bus system to respond to the changing patterns of the post-pandemic world—with twin goals of increasing ridership and improving equity.
Can New York City Go Green Without Renewable Rikers?
New York City’s bold proposal to close the jail on Rikers Island and replace it with green infrastructure is in jeopardy. Will this compromise the city’s ambitious climate goals?
700-Acre Master-Planned Community Planned in Utah
A massive development plan is taking shape for lakefront property in Vineyard, Utah—on the site of a former U.S. Steel Geneva Works facility.
More Cities Ponder the End of Drive-Thrus
Drive-thru fast food restaurants might be a staple of American life, but several U.S. cities are actively considering prohibiting the development of new drive-thrus for the benefit of traffic safety, air quality, and congestion.
Air Pollution World’s Worst Public Health Threat, Report Says
Air pollution is more likely to take years life off the lifespan of the average human than any other external factor, according to a recent report out of the University of Chicago.
Placer County
City of Morganton
HUD's Office of Policy Development and Research
Dongguan Binhaiwan Bay Area Management Committee
City of Waukesha, WI
Los Angeles County Metropolitan Transportation Authority
Indiana Borough
Write for Planetizen
Urban Design for Planners 1: Software Tools
This six-course series explores essential urban design concepts using open source software and equips planners with the tools they need to participate fully in the urban design process.
Planning for Universal Design
Learn the tools for implementing Universal Design in planning regulations.